Quantcast
Channel: UDADISI
Viewing all 468 articles
Browse latest View live

Dissociative Identity Disorder (DID)

$
0
0
Dissociative Identity Disorder (DID)
I try so hard to turn a blind eye
Telling me I’m not that guy
To worry about the worrying and dying 

I try so hard pretending it’s not my call
Coz I am no soldier, why bother about a brother
I am no judge, why bother about the oppressed
I am no Imam, why bother about the congregation 
I am no priest, why bother about the clergy
I am no damn politician, why waste time politicking

I am so cool dude, got none to do with the cruel
It’s you they are after, I’m the ever cool not to matter
But here still I am, finding it hard to taint the aim
Of making so much noise, causing a lot more trouble
For you already made it miserable, fooling yourself it’s honorable
But burying us deep under the rubble

It’s crumbling and falling and threatening 
You are fearful, it’s eating you, it will scrag you!!  

@Warumu
17thAugust 2019
Dar es Salaam

Me and You

$
0
0
Me and You

I used to see it in the news
Now I’m the news
I used to hear it from across the border
Now it’s around the corner

Dare not think, for it is fatal
Dare not question, for it is unpatriotic
Dare not opining, for it is puppetry
Dare not differ, for it is treason

Me be dumb, that I can’t
Come hurt me, for think I shall
Me be fool, that I can’t
Come suppress me, for question I shall
Me be quiet, that I can’t
Come torture me, for opining I shall
Me say sir yes sir, that I can’t
Come kill me, for youre a filthy murderer! 

@Warumu,
5thAugust 2019
Dar es Salaam

If I was IGP*

$
0
0

If I was IGP* 

If I was IGP 
Would I be VIP? 
And my people PIV? 
Poor Innocent Victims? 

Maybe I would wish to be president 
And command the residents 
To dutifully bow before my regiment 

When I am the IGP eeh! 
I would just want to be me 
Live in this professional bondage 
But consciously free 
Ain't that how things are supposed to be? 

Oh, if I was IGP 
I would be too general 
Not specifically targeting 
Those in different uniforms 
For they still conform 
To my content and form 

If I was IGP I would plead 
In this Island of peace 
The people ain't so free 
But that's not my decree 
So I will play by the rules 
Play by the books 
Not having to rue 
After I screw 
Up

*IGP - Inspector General of Police

@Nengwenengwe
18 August 2019
Dar es Salaam

Tears on our Flags

$
0
0
Tears on our Flags

Mwanahamisi 'Mishy' Singano



If only flags could have emotions, they would be shedding tears right now. Who wouldn’t be? I, for one, am angered! My tears are running dry. And my blood is boiling.

 To say we are in tough times in the continent is to put it mildly. Blood streams in Sudan have not dried (luckily, I hear there is a deal, finally). Streets in Zimbabwe are witnessing brutalization of the ‘people’, especially women. Petrol bombs are having a moment in Malawi. Stella Nyanzi is jailed for protesting against the master in Uganda and critics are being ‘dealt with’ where I come from. 
 I mean, the continent is full of conflicts fueled by patriarchal obsession of oppression and control of everything custodians of patriarchy believe they own, including our mind, emotions, and voices. 

Half a century ago, our flags were the sign of our liberation, the pride of our unity, and symbol of our triumph against brutal colonial regimes. I guess what we had won then, as a people, was the fight against (the white) colonialists. Sadly, we totally forget to win the fight against the oppressive rulers coming in different shapes, colors, and sizes. 
Now, we are embracing class divides. We, the ruled, are forced to assume that we are the same as the rulers, that we fought together for our freedom. Shamelessly, they even treat the rest of us as traitors if we dare question the smell of colonialism in them. 

Honestly, if you take a look left and right, you will clearly know and see our fights are different and our struggles are particular. We fought for their freedom to enslave and oppress us. What a mind game well played, African old boys’ club. 
Here I am, a faithful Pan-Africanist, preaching Ubuntu of African people, ready to go to war with anyone who profiles and stereotype Africans, vocal on the illicit financial flows from Africa, and foreign extraction of our precious natural resources. However, I know I should equally be vocal against internal extraction and corruption. Yes, and an active fighter of oppression within. 

 The truth is, it is easy and safe to question others but it takes dedication and bravery to fight your very own, especially when your own are senseless and the coldest; who will never blink an eye in televised conferences, condemning you for being prostitutes or members of organized crime, if you are lucky to escape framed money laundering and sedition charges or fortunate enough not to be abducted from out of nowhere and disappear with no trace. 
I am angered because I know what is right and what is wrong; I know this is not what we fought for. I hear noises and screams, “we need development before freedom and personal agency.” Gee! I am shocked, I thought we have settled that debate with the independent struggles and fight against colonialism. Or does that mean we have only fought against mzungu colonialists but we are super happy with the black ones? To put it bluntly, we are extremely brutalized economically, physically, and emotionally by our very own yet we feel ashamed and threatened to call it what it is - brutality. 
As a feminist, I can have a pass to say this because am used to be called and labeled ‘angry, emotional and often an irrational and desperate women.’ Yes, I am angry because my anger is the sum of the love I have for my people, the people I call friends, comrades, and family. I love them too much to the extent that their oppression becomes my oppression. 
I am angered of the hate rulers have towards the very same people who pledged on their behalf, in the name of the constitution, to protect, nurture, and love. I am angered by the hypocrisy of our people who see no reason to question, act or defend our rights to personal liberty and freedom. I am angered by those who tell me to use a decent language as if the oppressor oppresses us decently. 
Sadly, it is fashionable now to separate our spirit with what they call political. The underlying purpose is to legitimize oppression and limit resistance, leaving a few to take on the hard battle and become so exposed to highest level of retaliation by the black colonialists. The majority who consciously and/or unconsciously accept to be apolitical are left suffocated with illusions of safety and/or a desire to be promoted to the inner circle of the oppressors.
 The tears and sufferings of the significant few, who choose to fight oppression for all of us, are left to self-dry. I am afraid if we can’t cry with them and hold their heads up high with pride and dignity, their dried tears may be bloodstreams of many. May that bloody and gloomy doomsday not come.
 I am convinced our flags hanging on top of us are witnessing the pain in us. They, too, are in tears. But their resilience to stand tall come rain, came sun, should reminds us, as Audre Lorde recalls Malcolm X’s reminder, that "we are not responsible for our oppression, but we must be responsible for our own liberation."

Tija - Filamu Kuhusu Wahudumu wa Afya ya Jamii

I WILL PAY BACK YOUR MONEY AFTER SADC SUMMIT!

$
0
0
I WILL PAY BACK YOUR MONEY AFTER SADC SUMMIT!

Muhidin J. Shangwe

It has been a very busy August for Tanzania. Not without a good reason.

The 39th Southern African Development Community (SADC) Summit of the Heads of State and Government took place on 17th and 18th in Tanzania’s commercial capital of Dar es Salaam. It was a homecoming for the Community given Tanzania’s role in the liberation of nearly all SADC members from the clutches of colonialism and apartheid.

Several side events had taken place prior to the Summit, including the SADC 4th Industrial Week which took place from 5th to 9th. 

The build-up to the Summit had its own flashpoint. Paul Makonda, the Dar es Salaam Regional Commissioner (RC), for instance, issued a series of statements, which set the tone of what was coming ahead. 

For those unaware of Mr. Makonda’s portfolio, he represents the president in the administrative region of Dar es Salaam. Western media outlets have made it habit of referring to him as the city’s Governor as they struggle to comprehend this administrative structure, which has its roots deep into the colonial times. 

Since the Summit was to take place in his region, Mr. Makonda’s enthusiasm to play host was evident. It started with a meeting with journalists way back in May as part of an awareness campaign as he tasked them to ask the public questions about SADC to gauge their understanding of the bloc. There was a prize for those who would be deemed to have asked relevant questions. The results revealed worrying ignorance for anyone who cares, at least judging from responses which were posted online. This is for another day. 

In another move, traders at the famous sculpture market in Mwenge were told they could sell in the city center for visiting delegates. 

Dar was ready to impress. 

Then came the bombshell on July 28th when the RC announced that those who don’t wash their bodies and those who wear ragged, dirty clothes would be banned from the city center during the Summit. Ridiculous it may have sounded but the RC took his time to lecture on the level of personal hygiene acceptable in his city’s impromptu sanitation standards. 

As Dar dwellers were contemplating and some making mockery of the order, they must have been caught by surprise by what was to follow. The RC was at it again, announcing his plan to create a database of married men! He explained that it was an attempt to curb shameless cheating husbands who, scavenging without their wedding rings on, have left many hearts of young women broken with fake promises. 
Mr. Makonda revealed that he would use the Summit to learn the best practice on the issue from SADC members, an indication that this was, after all, a well-thought plan. Any good plan must be informed by good practice, mustn’t it? 

The move was a subject of ridicule and disapproval to a large extent, even after a prominent lawyer had explained the legal justification for it. Apparently, Tanzania has a law in its books that allows those affected by broken marriage promises to seek legal remedies within a year! Nevertheless, the anticipation of what was coming after the Summit was enough to create public suspense. 

The announcement followed a busy week of preparation for the Summit. Regular radio and TV ads and huge billboards on all the city’s major roads, had set the mood of and for a colossal gathering. But it was the married-men database which added an extra element in the public discourse. 
To give credit when it’s due, Mr. Makonda’s statements and orders did succeed in that SADC started to feature in average people’s informal conversation. This is despite the fact that all media outlets featured news about the SADC Summit on a daily basis. In an unprecedented move, the announcement made it to the The Shade Room, an American Instagram gossip page that has 16 million followers worldwide! 

Tanzanians are known for their sense of humor and they can be quite mean at that. In this case, humor was delivered in abundant supply. Netizens quickly seized the opportunity with a series of jokes that promised action but only after the Summit had ended. The one I found to be the funniest lamented about a regular loanee who, impliedly, had no business whatsoever with SADC, but, when asked to return the money to his creditor, he promised to do so after the Summit! 
Now, the Summit has since come to an end. How will the married-men database plan pans out?

New Series on ‘Tanzania Institutional Diagnostic’

$
0
0
This is an introduction to a series of commentaries that will be published here on Udadisi Blog for the next 7 days.

---

Tanzania Institutional Diagnostic: A Response and Comments 


At the REPOA Research Workshop in April 2019, Sam Wangwe and François Bourguignon presented a paper “Chapter 8: An Institutional Diagnostic of Tanzania: Synthesis”. It was clear that it was part of a bigger project. Subsequently I found an Introduction and 8 chapters on the web.

The Introductionexplains that this is part of a 5-year project, funded by UK Aid, based on a new approach to Institutionalism. Hitherto, most approaches to studies of institutions have either been historical studies of particular economies, or econometric studies using data from large numbers of economies. In contrast, this study, based mainly on documentary sources and interviews, is being conducted in just 4 countries (Mozambique, Bangladesh, Benin and Tanzania). It will seek to “identify major institutional obstacles to economic development in a specific country at a specific point of its development process, as well as possible lines of reform and the political economy issues associated with them” (p.6). Tanzania is the first country to report. Oxford University Press will publish a book or books based on the research.

The chapters are:

Part 1 – General Approach



Part 2 – Thematic Studies







When I read these, I realised that I had responses to every one of them. I wrote up my notes and sent them to the authors of Chapter 8. I received a reply to the effect that the authors will take them into account when they revise their chapters. This series of commentaries is a revised and reworked version of what I sent.

The collection of articles is path-breaking and will assist those who can make or influence policies, inside and outside Tanzania. Inevitably there are gaps, and places where the logic of arguments is not fully developed, or where similar material is covered in more than one place. It is a remarkable achievement to bring this material together. However, more could have, and can, be done, as my comments in the series make clear.

You Have No One To Blame, Not Even Yourself

$
0
0
You Have No One To Blame, Not Even Yourself

Take a deep breath

Baffled we were, with your performance as a Minister, in several Ministries, for several years
An exemplary public official, we saw in you!
By far, you outperformed your peers, so we believed
Enchanted, we became!

You bedazzled us with your mastery of statistics in your sectors
Readily regurgitating numbers of all fishes by species in all the seas, lakes, and rivers
Easily spewed up, to the nearest decimal points, kilometers of paved roads country wide

Freely disgorged numbers of cattle by geography, type and even pregnancy status
We swear! We believed all that!
A celebrity Minister, you were!

Who else deserved being your party’s flag bearer? We wondered!
The President of the United Republic, you became, eventually, naturally!
Jembe, tumepata” we chanted spiritedly
Chuma”, “Tinga Tinga”… It was a thrilling and surreal moment
Hapa Kazi tu” such an enthralling and captivating slogan
You set the bar very high!
Expectations were sky high!

Before we continue
Kindly remember,
You Have No One to Blame, Not Even Yourself

Now that … our eyes have seen the effects of your Government’s policies, actions, and words
Now that … our ears have heard the outcomes of your Government’s policies, actions, and words
Now that … our noses have smelled the stench of your Government policies, actions, and words
Now that … our bodies are devastated as we try to articulate what is going on
It is only logical that … our hearts are bleeding
It is only logical that … our heads are exploding

Perhaps, we are not the only ones suffering?
We have heard you, incessantly begging for our prayers
That is good, but we wonder…
What happened to the Kiranja wa Malaika?
And who are we to pray for him? We, his ungrateful subjects?
Why should we pray for him? Him, our Master, Mr. Perfect?

We trusted you!
We (unwillingly) agreed with you to push politics aside
We believed that you genuinely wanted to collaborate with us on the development agenda
Little did we know you would conjure some tricks up your sleeve
Swiftly uttered public statements to set the tone of the regime
Ushered in new laws to bolster your throne
Boldly took several actions to demonstrate that you meant business, not just mere words!

No more live broadcasting of the National Assembly proceedings
No more political rallies until next election season
No more unnecessary noise on (sic) imported human rights and democracy agenda
No more this, no more that…
…You and your subordinates would spit as you traversed the contours of this endowed land
Instantaneously and publicly, fired supposedly underperforming public officials. Tumbua majipu
Single handedly suffocated mafisadi … some of them are still in jail
Arguably, instilled a sense of discipline, efficiency, and effectiveness in the public sector
Disputably, also instilled a sense of job insecurity, fear, cowardice, hypocrisy. No?
Then reality dawned on us
The initial tinder has extinguished
Bad outcomes have masked the supposedly good intentions?
Perhaps a few anecdotes are worth recounting:
CAG reports methodically raise issues on management of public funds in every corner
The Judiciary is grappling with heaps of lawsuits filed against actions by the State and its organs and agents
The opposition emphatically criticized the regime’s policies, actions, and performance
The activists consistently interrogated the regime’s leadership style, priorities, strategies, and tactics
The development partners justly wondered about the blatant disregard of human rights and democratic principles
The media aptly amplified and widely circulated the dissenting voices before they were expeditiously quashed
The orchestrated exodus of opposition politicians joining the ruling party, fueled further internal party factions
Even the dissidents from within the ruling party and government were not left behind in venting their discontentment

Whoa!!
Such tenacious onslaught from all sides, it must have felt
Despair must have lingered in the air, everywhere
Feelings of betrayal, anger and being overwhelmed would be natural reactions

But, you – Jembe letu – never gave up
Fiercely marched forward
Alas! Decisions with worse consequences have been made
There exists an expansive and paralyzing list of bad laws enacted since
Very bad ones: the mere thought of them, makes one’s guts shudder
Laws that undeniably contravene the Constitution of the United Republic
Needless to say…
People have been abducted and attacked, by the unknowns who remain unknown for years now
People have disappeared, some reappeared, and others are yet to reappear
People have complained of unlawful arrests, detaining, and torture, so we have heard and seen
People have mysteriously died, dead bodies in viroba, dead bodies washing ashore - dead bodies galore!

Selectivity, the guiding principle, in deciding on when and how to intervene. So it seems!

Should you have done something, anything, everything as the custodian of people’s safety and security?

Sad…sad…sad!

A national moment of silence is in order
But what would it help anyway?

Should we remind you that your wananchi are no longer feeling safe in their own country?
Should we remind you that your country is no longer that idealized island of peace?
And do you need to be reminded that your country’s reputation and image locally and internationally, is tainted?

And remember that,
You Have No One to Blame, Not Even Yourself
Can you attempt some damage control?
We believe you have the reason, time, and resources to do so
We do not believe that you have the right team to control the damage
Maybe some are hypocrites? Maybe some are genuinely cowards?
And maybe some have the competencies but stifled and paralyzed by the culture of hypocrisy (majungu na fitna) engulfing them?

Unquestionably, you have deliberately thwarted virtually any critical and constructive feedback
Erroneously, you have apparently pushed away all actors with constitutional rights and strategic competences to help you
Disappointingly, you have hired and fired many but more often than not to no good results
Unsurprisingly, you have boxed in yourself with your few loyal advisors, again with unconvincing results

Do not blame them when they let you down
They are simply trying to impress or emulate you
Remember, they are paralyzed to inaction by the culture of hypocrisy that seems to thrive effortlessly

Finally,
You have told us that if you knew what the presidency entailed, you would have thought twice about it
You have told us that you do not sleep well at night because the job is overwhelming
But we truly believe you knew what you were getting yourself into

We are not going to attempt to pretend to offer you some advice
We know you will do exactly the opposite of what we would advise

You have no one to blame, not even yourself!

Please remember that!

@Concerned Citizen, 22 August 2019

Coulson: On Political and Economic Development

$
0
0
This is Part 1 of a series of commentaries on Udadisi Blog entitled Tanzania Institutional Diagnostic: A Response and Comments By Andrew Coulson


This chapter, by François Bourguignon, has three sections: a summary of Tanzania’s political and economic history; a review of the macroeconomic data; and a discussion of some of the information on education and healthcare.

It is hard to write a convincing summary of the history of a country in less than 10 pages, so there are bound to be gaps, but here are some of the points that struck me when I read it:

Tanzanian history did not begin with the German conquest. There was an active empire with its capital in Zanzibar, and increasing trade inland before the Germans, as well as many craft skills. There was also slavery, though not on a scale comparable to that in West Africa. 

The Germans were incredibly productive in a very few years (that is after they won militarily and created a new state): they mapped the whole country, discovered most of the minerals, conducted pioneering medical and veterinary research, built the Dar es Salaam to Kigoma and Tanga to Moshi railways, and created a new capital and harbour in Dar es Salaam. Governor Rechenberg in particular was not purely authoritarian. The return of the tsetse fly was related to the wars of conquest – when there is human habitation the fly are controlled; in times of war the people move to a few places to seek safety and the fly return. The situation was bad following the Maji Maji rebellion, but probably even worse during and after World War 1, when German and British armies largely lived off the land.

Tanganyika under British governance was neglected, especially when compared with settler colonies such as Kenya and Zimbabwe. But after World War 2 there was more interest. The Groundnuts Scheme was a classic failure of large scale agriculture – but there were similar failures post-Independence (the Basotu Wheat Scheme of the late 1970s, and the agricultural aspects of Big Results Now in the 2000s). Coffee and cotton were developed for export markets, adding to sisal which expanded earlier. By the time of Independence, there was close cooperation between the British administrators and the nationalist politicians.

Nyerere was very cautious about the Soviet Union and countries in the Soviet sphere of interest. He was more influenced by the Fabian socialist thinking which he encountered in Edinburgh, and he resisted strategies based on heavy industry, and attacks on “kulaks” when these were advocated by some of his political colleagues, such as Abdul Rahman Babu. If anything he and the country were closer to the Chinese. 

Sisal exports declined because their main uses – string to tie up parcels and ropes for ships – were replaced by cheaper and lighter plastic-based substitutes. Tanzania did export food in some years, but it also imported food.

The war with Amin was quite short. I have often wondered why it appears to have consumed so many resources, and suspect that it was followed by a heavy investment in the military.

I have little to add to what is written about the years of structural adjustment etc. I did not visit Tanzania in that period, or keep up to date as the situation developed.

Pp.10-26 is an important review of the macro-economic data for Tanzania. In terms of GDP the country has done well since the turn of the millennium. No sector became a dominant “growth centre” in this period, with much of the growth coming from a movement out of agriculture, where productivity is low, into other sectors where it is higher. In terms of trade, the biggest increases in exports came from gold and tourism, but imports have exceeded exports – with the balance made up from overseas “aid” and government borrowing. 30% of GDP is invested – a high figure – but it does not appear to have been invested particularly well, or growth would have been even higher. The net borrowing from overseas reached 33% of GDP in 2015, which is sustainable as long as international borrowing rates stay low, but will quickly become a big problem if they rise.
There are many places in this narrative where difficulties with the data are acknowledged, most where different sources give different figures for what should be the same. It may be that the data we have is better than not having any data. But I think that the problems are even worse than described. Difficulties with the data on small-scale agriculture were discussed by Skarstein (in Havnevik and Isinika (eds.) Tanzania in Transition: From Nyerere to Mkapa, 2010 pp.99-130), and in an Annex of the Agriculture Sector Development Programme Phase Two (ASDP II) in 2016. 

My interpretation: agricultural censuses produce a baseline for the areas devoted to different crops. But yields and prices vary greatly from year to year and in different parts of the country and are much harder to estimate. In colonial times and when I worked in the Ministry of Agriculture in the 1960s, District Agricultural Officers were rung up on the telephone and asked to make estimates of by how much yields were likely to be higher or lower than the previous year – not reliable but it explains some of the contradictions. This fell into disuse when the agricultural officers concerned became employed by district councils, and could not be forced to respond to requests from the Ministry. I am told that there are better methods now, including use of aerial photos, but I am not sure that the task is possible. 

There are even bigger problems with prices, e.g. if there is a good yield of cashewnut or maize but the farmers are paid half of what they were promised, or payments to them are delayed, how do you value the crop in GDP calculations? Or if a very good crop of tomatoes rots in the field? Should you value a food crop such as maize which is consumed locally at its value that would have been achieved if it was sold, or its value if the farmer or producer had to buy it at the end of a long dry season, when its value is much higher? Should the same price/value for food crops such as maize or bananas be used for the whole country? 
There are issues of smuggling and associated under-reporting (see Lofchie, The Political Economy of Tanzania: Decline and Recovery, 2014, p.167 for a telling paragraph on the smuggling of raw coffee to Kenya). One of the challenges is that there has been a green revolution in the South, Rukwa and parts of central Tanzania, based on hybrid maize and sunflower, potatoes, tobacco, cashewnut and other crops. However, climate change, plant diseases (affecting bananas in particular) and declines in both prices and quantities of coffee and cotton have turned what were, not long ago, the success areas of Northern Tanzania into huge challenges. Figures for the country as a whole do not reflect this diversity (See Figure Below from ASDP II, 2017).
There are issues with the informal sector generally. Rizzo (Taken for a Ride, 2017, esp. pp.76-8) pointed out that a problem with the translation of the labour force surveys into Swahili has led to most of those in the informal sector who work for others (e.g. on daladalas) being recorded as self-employed – thereby overestimating the number of businesses and underestimating their scale. But generally, in rural areas as well as urban, the sector is growing so fast that it is very hard to keep track. For example, artisanal mining has in recent years employed more than a million people (see Bryceson and Geenen in African Affairs, Feb 2016, and work by Sarah Hayes for the World Bank).
The dark sector is even more of a problem. Smuggling, to avoid local taxes and cesses as well as border controls, is significant. It is alleged that most of the property boom in high-rise buildings in Dar es Salaam is based on money laundered from the Middle East – I have no evidence for this. Lofchie (pp.137-9; p.151ff.) describes the various forms of rent-seeking that emerged due to the overvalued exchange rate in the 1980s. Those who could persuade the Bank of Tanzania (BOT) to give them dollars in exchange for shillings, could import goods and sell them for many more shillings – and go back to the BOT for more dollars (pp.168-9). But, he argues, many other members of the elite made money by making and selling goods, and the reforms of the Mwinyi period were acceptable because this group of salaried individuals realised that they would find it easier to make money from businesses if they could do so legally (pp.41-2; 151-161). But if individuals could play the currency markets like this, how much more so companies which were regularly involved in importing?

The discussion of poverty and inequality again highlights almost insuperable disparities between the different sources of data, though none of them doubt that “there is a challenge in transforming GDP growth into poverty reduction” ( p.30) – i.e. not much of the growth has trickled down.

How should scholars respond to these huge problems with the data? The most common approach, followed here with great diligence, is to study the different sources and make judgements about which is the most plausible for any particular figure. But this gives a spurious impression of accuracy. Maybe every figure should be given a range of possible values. Or any figure for which there is more than one official estimates should be marked with a *.
 Perhaps it is time, in a country study such as this, to question the utility of the international systems of statistics, and in particular GDP as a measure. It has been controversial ever since its creation by Kusnets, Richard Stone and others in the 1940s. There are fundamental problems about valuing investment, unpaid labour such as housework or care of elderly relatives, environmental externalities, and public services provided by states (customarily included as the value of wages and salaries paid to those involved, which makes no allowances for differences in quality or productivity). It makes no allowances for inequalities, or (un)happiness. The difficulties/disagreements are bad enough in developed countries, but far worse in countries such as Tanzania. So possibly the author should have concluded that GDP for Tanzania is uncertain, and given more weight to figures which are collected as part of public administration – imports and exports, taxation, employment in the formal sectors.

Pp.31-5 report on education and health. It is helpful to highlight the weaknesses in the quality of education, lack of teacher skills, and absenteeism, and the lack of attention given to technical training programmes. Similar points could be made about the Higher Education (university) sector. And to point to the failure to deliver budgets for basic medical services. The institutions involved could have been the subject of chapters in their own right, as could other services devolved to district councils – agricultural and livestock extension, domestic water supplies, feeder roads, etc. The discussion of decentralisation in Ch.5 is about tax revenues and the income side of budgets, whereas an institutional approach cries out for focus on functions and expenditure, such as how allocations of drugs for rural dispensaries are managed, or whether the village-based extension service can be effective without better links with research stations and without adequate transport.

Coulson: On Insights for Institutional Diagnostic

$
0
0
This is Part 2 of a series of commentaries on Udadisi Blog entitled Tanzania Institutional Diagnostic: A Response and Comments By Andrew Coulson

Chapter 2: Collecting Insights for an Institutional Diagnostic of Development

This chapter, by François Bourguignon and François Libois, brings together information about the major institutional challenges to development in Tanzania. More than half the chapter reports on questionnaires administered to a sample of 101 elite Tanzanian decision-makers. These include politicians, administrators or civil servants (including those from the justice system, the military, and the foreign service, as well as public administration), business people, and those from civil society. To select the sample “REPOA, in co-operation with Oxford Policy Management, determined a list of target respondents who satisfied the occupational, geographical and gender considerations”. They interviewed these respondents, asking them for their opinions, on a scale of 1-5, on a long list of topics; the most significant were corruption, land issues, the absence of effective regulation especially of infrastructure, and lack of transparency.
83 of the 101 were male (but this does not stop the authors making comparisons between male and female responses – women turned out to be much more concerned about all kinds of discrimination than men), 95% of them were living in urban areas, and just over a third were “directly involved in politics”, divided equally between supporters of the Government and the Opposition. By far the greatest numbers in the sample were born in Dar es Salaam, Moshi, Arusha, Tanga, Kagera or Mwanza – the Southern and South-Western parts of the country were under-represented. 
The questionnaire-based interviews were supplemented by unstructured interviews: “several experts, some of whom are at the highest level of responsibility in the country, were interviewed on an informal or open-ended basis” – about 50 in total.
The chapter then turns to internationally available data from different sources. Very large numbers of indicators were grouped into clusters, six of which were deemed to be most significant: democracy, human rights, administrative capacity, rule of law and corruption, conflict and violence, and competitiveness. Comparisons of these are made with the six countries that border Tanzania, and with five Asian countries. Tanzania outperforms many of its neighbours on all six indicators, and compares very favourably with the five Asian countries. These results are unexpected, to say the least. 
Perhaps many Tanzanians underestimate the levels, and successes, of their economic growth, because only a little of it trickles down to them. Many middle level government employees face this personally, not least because the President has removed many fringe benefits, such as cash allowances for attending conferences and meetings. So, for example, numbers of African Tanzanians able to afford to send their children to elite English-language schools, such as Morogoro International School, have fallen.
The limitations of this kind of methodology are apparent: the surveys are dependent on the selection of the sample and the questions asked. There should have been many more women in the samples, and more effort to get representation from across the country. A deeper criticism is that they reflect what is actually going on but not necessarily what should be. Thus, there is no mention here of global heating (climate change), or population growth. 
The official line, reasserted by the President, is that population growth is good, and a population of 100m will make Tanzania a powerful state on the world stage. Economists, overwhelmingly, see rapid population growth as making it harder to get rises in GDP per capita and finding employment a greater challenge. In our book on agriculture we suggest that small scale agriculture is the only way of providing jobs on the required scale – a reserve army of labour, but not one likely to be called on much (Coulson, Ellman and Mbiho, Increasing Production from the Land: A Sourcebook on Agriculture for Teachers and Students in East Africa, Mkuki na Nyota, 2018). Arthur Lewis had good instincts. Even keeping a large part of the population alive may not be easy to achieve, given global heating, soil degradation, declining sizes of plots in mountain areas, etc. 
I partly blame myself and colleagues for Tanzania’s uncritical response to population growth: in the 1970s we taught a very strong anti-Malthusian message – but when I left the country in 1976 the population was only 16 million! China’s GDP is growing at 6-10%, but its population is reducing, as a result of the draconian one-child policy. I doubt if that would ever be accepted in an African country. But it means that there are that much more resources available to ensure that almost everyone can get an uplift.

COULSON: ON BUSINESS AND POLITICS

$
0
0
This is Part 3 of a series of commentaries on Udadisi Blog entitled Tanzania Institutional Diagnostic: A Response and Comments By Andrew Coulson

Chapter 3: Politics and Business

Samuel Wangwe has a lifetime of research and writing on industrialisation in Tanzania, and it comes to the fore here on chapter 3. He also makes very good use of other sources especially Barker et al.’s African Industrialisation: Technology and Change in Tanzania (1986), Bryceson’s Liberalizing Tanzania’s Food Trade(1993), and Gibbon’s (ed.), Liberalised Development in Tanzania(1995). 
However, two recent publications take the historiography to another dimension: 

Chambi Chachage’s A Capitalizing City: Dar es Salaam and the Emergence of an African Entrepreneurial Elite (c.1862-2015). Doctoral dissertation, Harvard University, 2018

The first part of Chambi’s dissertation is a retelling of the history of capitalism in the colonial period and early years of Independence. Much of it is a reworking of John Iliffe’s (ed.) classic mini-biographies of the African capitalist pioneers and their struggles. The later part includes mini-biographies of key members of the current business elite, and the many challenges they have faced, and, for them at least, overcome. It will be published as a book in the not-too-distant future.
In my opinion, the Mufuruki book is profound not only because of the originality of some of its proposals, but because it is a political statement of a successful Tanzanian businessman (his life story is summarised in Chambi’s dissertation). His main intellectual influences are Ha-Jung Chang and Justin Lin, basically following the South Asian model (Vietnam, Malaysia and, implicitly South Korea). It is a sad reflection on the discourse in Tanzania that it was not widely discussed after its launch, and is only now being taken more seriously. For me that says a lot about who controls the Tanzanian agenda on industrial strategy – a group including key donors, politicians and economists. The Mufuruki book was produced outside this framework, and said things many in this group did not want to hear – such as that energy policy should not be so dependent on gas and oil. It also supports what amounts to the Ethiopian strategy for labour-intensive export-oriented manufacturing, e.g. of textiles or shoes, which has been rejected, or not accepted, by most of the Tanzanian policy-makers. 

There have been times, attending REPOA Annual Research Workshops, when I felt that Tanzania was being offered a different industrial strategy each year, without relating it to, or comparing it with, what had been said in the previous years. Thus, Justin Lin was the keynote speaker in 2016, and proposed a version of the Ethiopia strategy. Lant Pritchett was the keynote speaker the next year, and offered different advice, to the effect that the best strategy was to export as many different products as possible. No one pointed out that this was diametrically opposed to what Lin said the previous year.

COULSON: ON THE CIVIL SERVICE AND DEVELOPMENT

$
0
0
This is Part 4 of a series of commentaries on Udadisi Blog entitled Tanzania Institutional Diagnostic: A Response and Comments By Andrew Coulson

Chapter 4: The Civil Service and Economic Development

If you have time to read just one of the chapters here, it should be this one [by Rwekaza Mukandala with Discussion by Jan Willem Gunning]. It provides detailed descriptions of how, since Independence, the civil service in Tanzania has struggled to make, even to develop, policies, because so much has been taken over by politicians. The country has moved from being one of the least corrupt (at the time of and after the Arusha Declaration) to one of the most.
Jan Willem Gunning, in a thoughtful commentary, points out that, in a democracy, politicians should be elected on the basis of promises to implement specific policies – and civil servants put those policies into effect. In reality, in a complex society, many new policies derive from civil servants, but the process of putting them into effect involves a complex interplay with politicians, who have views on how they should be implemented, and have to steer the proposals through Parliament. 

Gunning also points out that there is some confusion in the chapter, especially when it draws on statistics. Thus, in a strict sense, a civil servant is any person who is directly employed by a government – from very junior clerks and (say) watchmen who happen to be employed by the state, to highly specialised technicians such as those who work in various inspectorates, or as judges or magistrates or in research stations, right through to the elite group (in the UK the “executive grades”) who make policy. But the term is also used to describe just the elite managers who head departments or divisions of departments, and that is what most of the chapter is about. A statistical annex, which included figures over time for the numbers of different types of civil servants, would have been a useful addition to the chapter and clarified some of these issues. 
As Mukandala notes, at Independence in 1961, Tanzania “had 21 graduates, out of whom 11 were indigenous Africans” (p.3). To fill the top posts, staff were moved in from other services, especially teaching, or promoted very quickly. It was a major achievement to keep the civil service operational with so little local technical expertise and practical experience.

Inevitably, others were brought in from outside the country. I was a civil servant in the Ministry of Agriculture from 1967-1971. My work, relating to foreign-aided projects, required me to support the senior civil servants in the HQ of the Ministry. They included, until 1968, the remaining “permanent and pensionable” civil servants who had served in the colonial civil service, most as Provincial or District Commissioners or agricultural officers of various specialisms. The Ministry also employed expatriates on contracts (such as me) who did not have previous experience in Tanzania. Most of the Heads of Departments were African Tanzanians - the first generation to be appointed to these roles.
The expertise of some (but by no means all) of the foreigners was very high. To give one illustration, Nicholas Monck, who sadly died recently, studied at Eton College and Cambridge University, and came on secondment from the UK Treasury in 1967 when he realised that he was unlikely to be promoted in the next 3 years. He later became Permanent Secretary of the UK Ministry of Employment and the first UK civil servant to be made a director of a UK nationalised industry (the British Steel Corporation). He was one of the most senior UK civil servants who was also a member of the Labour Party. In Tanzania he headed the team responsible for crop marketing, which included setting the pan-territorial prices, which was done with great care. [Incidentally, apropro pan-territorial pricing, mentioned on p.8, in at least two places Marc Wuyts has recently defended it, as a form of infant-industry protection, no doubt expensive, but it made it possible for crops such as maize to be grown for sale in remote parts of Tanzania, such as Rukwa or Songea].
Different issues apply to the different kinds of civil service employment. Thus, again from my experience, ten years after I had left Tanzania, in 1986, I was employed as a short-term consultant to help NORAD decide whether to continue its support for the Department of Chemistry at the University of Dar es Salaam. The methodology involved identifying as many recent graduates of the Department as possible to find what they were doing. Many were working in the labs of large companies, such as Kilombero Sugar Co. They were using their technical skills as chemists. But there was little expectation that many of them would move on to become the top decision-makers. We recommended that NORAD continue its support, and that the University maintain its chemistry department not just to train teachers but also technicians such as these – alongside the rapidly developing chemical engineering/process engineering department in the Faculty of Engineering. 

Project-aid has had some unintended consequences. A project is created to address a problem. That project includes post-graduate training in regard to that problem, often in the donor country. It also includes a new building for a new institute in Tanzania. Those trained come back, influenced by practice in the country where they have been trained, and take over the project. What they should do, or be prepared to do, is to move into the civil service and use the skills they have gained to develop their technical area. But they are likely to be better paid and with much less stress if they stay with the project. The result is many NGOs and institutes, with complex relationships with the civil service. This may not be the best way to use the skills of those who have been trained abroad.
There is much in this chapter about corruption and how to deal with it, about the motivation of civil servants, about the need to deal with scandals such as “ghost workers”, absentee teachers, and high vacancy rates, the need for competence and performance evaluation, and moral and professional incentives. It is notable for not proposing a reduction in numbers, or more privatization.

Coulson: On Decentralisation

$
0
0
This is Part 5 of a series of commentaries on Udadisi Blog entitled Tanzania Institutional Diagnostic: A Response and Comments By Andrew Coulson

Chapter 5: Decentralisation

I spent the last 25 years of my salaried employment working in the Institute of Local Government Studies (INLOGOV), at Birmingham University, the leading institution studying local government in the UK. I worked on local government finance, then developed the Institute’s work on local economic development, and ended working on local politics, especially the “scrutiny” function, how councillors can hold council officials to account.
Most writing on decentralisation to regions, districts, cities or towns, or villages focuses either on finance, or on function, not on both of them. This chapter [by Jan Willem Gunning], interesting as it is, is about finance and says little about the possible functions of local government – which functions should be devolved, and how they can balance the advantages of being nearer to the people with the disadvantages of not always being up to date, or of being “parochial” i.e. not seeing beyond their own boundaries.
Many problems of the district councils in Tanzania relate to function – how do they decide which feeder roads to maintain? How many dispensaries to open if they cannot be sure of the drugs to supply them? How much resource to devote to maintaining rural water supply infrastructure constructed in the 1970s? How to use the agricultural extension service effectively when most of the extension officers are not up to date in their technical knowledge about crops and their pests and diseases, or aware of short-term changes in prices etc.?
The chapter does not consider what is not decentralised, e.g. the police and judiciary, or the various inspectorates. Or of scale – is there a case for elected councils for regions and districts, with Regional Commissioners and District Commissioners replaced by Council Leaders? Would Dar es Salaam be better with an elected council for the Region rather than separate councils for 5 districts? 
It is hard to disagree with its main conclusion, that revenue is best collected centrally and divided between councils using a formula. Of course this means that the Centre controls the money, and, when push comes to shove, will boss the districts – especially if many of them, and many of the most important, are controlled by Opposition parties.
However, more could usefully have been said about the disastrous practice of agreeing budgets for a year on the basis that they will only be funded once the revenue is raised. This has kept the spending on local government under some sort of control. But has had the result that district councils often make promises which they are unable to fulfil. It would be better to have less ambitious budgets which are contractually agreed with central government, which can be supplemented if more revenue becomes available.
In most European states and parts of Asia, local government of cities and towns existed before central government – and in America from the 1790s all city councils were run by representatives elected by people who lived there (but it was far from a universal franchise – those who could vote were male and owners of property, and hence white). There are proud traditions of local self-government across mainland Europe, with councils responsible for basic services elected in small towns or villages. But the advent of welfare states which provide expensive professionalised services, led to councils for much larger areas – or several tiers of councils such as the communes, départements and régions in France. Service delivery may be contracted out to private companies, e.g. collection of domestic waste, or maintenance of roads, but this requires the council to have the expertise as client to manage the resulting contracts so as not to be exploited. 
African countries have had to create such structures with much less history. Looking at it the other way round, Tanzania is a very big state, and it is not possible or desirable for all decisions to be taken at the centre – people need to be able to make decisions locally, and to be held accountable for them – but, as the chapter makes clear, this is not without costs and it needs specialist expertise with integrity, e.g. auditors, inspectors, etc. This chapter is very good on what it covers, but there are large areas, and big challenges, which are only mentioned in passing.

COULSON: ON LAND RIGHTS

$
0
0
This is Part 6 of a series of commentaries on Udadisi Blog entitled Tanzania Institutional Diagnostic: A Response and Comments By Andrew Coulson

Chapter 6: Land Rights

I have read several attempts to describe the confused position of land rights in Tanzania, and this chapter [by S.J. Mramba with discussion by Klaus Deininger ] is comprehensive, well-informed and practical. However, it is not an easy read: I would recommend readers to first read Deininger’s four page commentary at the end of the chapter, which provide a clear summary of practical proposals to improve both urban and rural land tenure.

Turning to the chapter, I would have liked more recognition that land is a form of property, and that control of land is an exercise of power, and that sometimes power is exercised to prevent change or reform. I do not think it is coincidental that the 1999 legislation has not been reformed, because there are individuals and classes that benefit from the present confused situation. There is some political economy in the chapter, e.g. pp.3-4 and the mention of Shivji’s position on p.6, but there could have been more.
One significant development is not discussed – though the comments about bias against villagers and enclosures of “commons” in Para 6.2 are consistent with it (note – the page numbering in this chapter is confusing). It is set out in a paper by a team led from Michigan State University (MSU) by Thomas Jayne et al.: “Africa’s changing farm size distribution patterns: the rise of medium-scale farms”Agricultural Economics Vol. 47, 2016. They present evidence that huge transfers of land are taking place, in Ghana, Kenya, Tanzania and Zambia, to middle-class salaried professionals who are purchasing agricultural land cheaply, without, in the main, living on the farms. This provides a new and valuable source of capital for investment in agriculture. But many of these investors have little experience, or understanding of the risks, and some are not using the land at all, and risk having it taken back. Overall, it is a form of land-grabbing that far exceeds anything by overseas investors. 
The Jayne paper quotes fieldwork by a team at Sokoine University of Agriculture (SUA) led by Prof Ntengua Mdoe, but I am told that this is not yet ready for publication. Much of this land is in marginal areas, such as Kiteto District in Tanzania, the South-Eastern part of Maasailand, where the Mdoe team identified 3668 farms of more than 5 ha. In the past, there are examples where mechanisation has been applied to marginal land such as this with initial success, but it has led to very serious soil erosion and failure (e.g. the Ismani area North of Iringa in the 1970s). 

Much of this land has been used by pastoralists, and continues the grabbing of such land for crop cultivation that was found, for example, in the Groundnuts Scheme or the Basotu Wheat Scheme of the late 1970s and 1980s. But perhaps much more is land that has not been cultivated since the villagizations of the 1970s. Many farmers who were compulsorily moved into villages were given plots far from where they had lived. The land they had cultivated, often with higher quality of soils than where they were moved to, was abandoned. Some of this is now being “sold” to these investors by village committees – for, I was told, a going price of T.Shs.1m per acre, i.e. very cheaply indeed. 
But meanwhile the forms of shifting cultivation, which enabled the fertility of large areas of land to be maintained are no longer possible, and from the 1970s farmers had no option but to adopt permanent cropping. They had little guidance on how to introduce rotations, crops and cultivation practices that will maintain fertility – and yields are falling. In earlier times, when fertility dropped, a family could ask the chief, or village leader, for more land – but with villagization plots became much more inflexible. How to treat this was a challenge when it came to our book on agriculture (Coulson, Ellman and Mbiho, Increasing Production from the Land, 2018). We dealt with it by avoiding the issue directly and pointing out that productivity increases are possible at all scales. 
The issue of land grabbing by overseas investors would have been more contentious if five large projects based on cultivation of biofuels had succeeded. The most specific research on this, which includes comments on all identifiable large-scale proposals, is by Martina Locher and Emmanuel Sulle: ‘Foreign Land Deals in Tanzania: An Update and a Critical Review on the Challenges of Data (Re-)production’, Working Paper 31, Land Deals Policy Initiative, 2013; and ‘Challenges and Methodological Flaws in Reporting the Global Land Rush: Observations from Tanzania’Journal of Peasant Studies Vol.41, No.3-4, 2014. [Note: the author referred to below Box 5 and in the bibliography is Sulle not Sule.]
Deininger’s commentary at the end of the chapter provides four pages which “provide concrete next steps that could allow Tanzania to improve land tenure security at a scale similar to that in Rwanda without giving up some of the distinctive characteristics of land tenure in Tanzania.” One of the main conclusions of the chapter, of the final chapter, p.16, and of the commentary is that rapid surveying of village land, using aerial photos, followed by the issue of titles whose details can be clarified subsequently, needs to be conducted for the whole country, urgently, as it has been for Rwanda. 
Why has this not been done? Maybe because it is opposed by those who are able to purchase land cheaply now. But if the rural areas are to provide a basic living for a large part of the population of Tanzania, they must have security of tenure.

Barbaric!

$
0
0
Barbaric!
We thought it was for liberation and development,
We thought it was for independence, freedom, peace and democracy,
We thought it was for diversity, tolerance and progress,
That’s what we signed up for, didn’t we? 
It’s what we fought for!

Now tell me my comrades,
Were we promised restraint,
And being served with a siege,
By the tyranny we did not foresee,
To which subservience is sacred!

Oh! Tell me they were dreams and fantasies?
For now we have to fight again, just to breathe,
Only that we can see, hear, smell, 
Taste and touch,
A barbaric fight indeed, just for our life!

@Warumu
12/09/2019

COULSON: ON THE POWER SECTOR

$
0
0
This is Part 7 of a series of commentaries on Udadisi Blog entitled Tanzania Institutional Diagnostic: A Response and Comments By Andrew Coulson


Chapter 7: The Power Sector

Since 1992, The Tanzania Electric Supply Company Limited (TANESCO) and the Bank of Tanzania (BOT) have been involved in a series of corruption scandals, in which money was syphoned off to finance political campaigns. Before that, and in the early years of Independence, TANESCO was a model parastatal, drawing, I guess, much of its inspiration and practice from the Central Electricity Generating Board (CEGB) in the UK. It was not short of money, so paid its staff good wages and delivered a quality service, to those who could afford to pay for it, mainly in the cities (especially Dar es Salaam) and towns, and in rural areas where there were processing factories for tea, sisal, sugar that needed reliable power supplies. Supply was increased to meet demand, so regular power cuts were much less than now, and faults were usually repaired reasonably quickly.

A consequence of the recent history of corruption is that the writing in this chapter [by Catrina Godinho and Anton Eberhard with discussion by A. Estache ] is noticeably more strident than earlier chapters.

The chapter is about the power sector. If it had included more about energy policy generally, it would have needed a consideration of how to phase out the use of charcoal as the main source of energy for cooking – which is having devastating effects on forests, as trees are cut down in more and more remote areas, but also on public health as families breath in the smoke, in homes where the fuel is burned in the main living area, but also in urban areas such as Dar es Salaam where it is a major contributor to the air pollution often visible when driving down the hills towards the city along the Morogoro Road. This will, in a generation or so, lead to an epidemic of lung cancer. On the other hand, charcoal production is a major provider of employment, and one that unskilled people can take part in. There are also powerful vested interests that control the urban trade. So it is a daunting task even to hold production where it is now.

There is also little in this chapter about global warming [there is a feeling now in the UK that this language is too gentle – better to call it global heating or climate emergency]. If a chapter on the power sector had been written for a Western country, this would have been a central theme. Is it not patronising to imply that Tanzania can stand aside from this – when manufacturing and transport across the whole planet is being re-engineered to use less carbon?
The key source of energy for generation of electricity in Tanzania should be solar, as suggested by Estache in his commentary on the chapter and Mufuruki et al. (Tanzania's Industrialization Journey, 2017). Estache includes references on renewable energy solutions, low cost solar power, and mini-grids, but does not provide much detail. These can be far more than add-ons in semi-rural areas far from the main grid. In the UK farmers are converting large fields into solar generating stations, and wind is now the cheapest source of electricity. Tanzania has reliable sun and regular 12-hour days and land which is not suitable for agriculture and can be converted into solar farms. This is one of the main proposals in the Mufuruki book. The technologies for storing heat or electricity are improving rapidly, e.g. storing heat as hot water, or hydrogen, and mega-batteries, and Tanzania also has reserves of hydro power which could be kept back for use in the nights, and regular winds. What Tanzania should not do is use gas to generate electricity, which will contribute to global heating but is also a low-return use of the gas.
Mufuruki et al. suggest (on p.88) that the state should make a commitment that that every household should have at least 150-200 watts of electricity by 2025 – sufficient for basic lighting, domestic appliances such as fridges, some cooking, and the running of basic tools such as drills or welding machines or water pumps. In most places this would come from solar, and it would be delivered by the private sector - providing an important new source of employment in the manufacture of the panels as well as in their installation and maintenance.

In larger settlements it makes sense to network the houses and for the provider to supply the machine that convert DC current to AC, so that any surplus can be fed back into the grid, with the town or village getting paid (on a “buy-back tariff”) and making useful income. In many advanced countries such as the UK, this is resisted by the major interests that supply electricity who much prefer a few large power stations, but these vested interests need to be challenged, and the sooner the better.
The chapter does not discuss Steigler’s Gorge. President Magufuli has made it a priority. He tore up the contract with the Brazilian company Odebrechtthat Kikwete had negotiated, and signed a new contract with an Egyptian contractor where the financing is not included. The preliminary work has already led to thousands of trees being cut down, and great intrusion into the Selous Game Reserve. The environmental case against it is formidable – not just the loss of trees and habitats but the loss of the highly productive agriculture in the flood plain, and both inland fisheries (which will be lost because the ox-bow lakes will become saline) and sea fisheries (because there will be less nutrients in the water). If smaller dams are not built on tributary rivers, the Steigler’s Gorge lake will fill up from silt running off the land, especially if global heating leads to more big storms in the dry seasons. 
Benno Ndulu has strong views about the likely downsides of the dam – he was employed as a research assistant and co-authored a paper about it, when a masters student in the 1970s. The issues have not changed since then. Except that population is much more, and that no-one at that time envisaged a standard-gauge electrified railway, which if it is successful, and runs trains at high speeds, will require a lot of electricity. Or the extent of global heating. Antonio Andreoni, at a Britain Tanzania Society seminar in London, suggested that the Tanzanian state is happier dealing with a single large supplier, and a single contract, than with many smaller suppliers each with a contract to be supervised and monitored. If this is correct it is another illustration of the State being reluctant to trust the private sector. (For my summary of points made at the seminar, see https://www.britaintanzaniasociety.co.uk/xxx/).
It is easy to understand why this chapter is more strident than the other chapters. Yet care should be taken about generalising from this. Some of Magufuli’s interventions have had spectacular results. By going eyeball-to-eyeball with Dangote, he achieved much lower prices for cement, to the great benefit of all involved in construction. His intervention to publicise the illegal export of mineral sands led to major concessions from Acacia. He was prepared to tear up contracts with Odebrecht for Steigler’s Gorge, and with the Chinese for the Liganga/Muchuchuma iron ore/steel/titanium/ vanadium/coal development in the SW of the country. He achieved much lower prices per kilometre for the standard gauge railway than in Kenya. If this can open up the corridor from Uganda (and Burundi and Rwanda) to the Tanzanian coast, there will be many benefits from cross-border trade.
The writers seem disappointed at the end of Big Results Now (BRN), which was innovative both in its involvement of Malaysian technocrats from PERMANDU, their Management and Delivery Unit, and the use of “labs” in which groups of experts were almost locked away until they had come up with key proposals for their sector. One of these was Energy, interpreted as electricity, another was Transport, focussed on the port of Dar es Salaam. But BRN was abandoned in 2016. Why? Probably the main failure was the lack of any link between those who created the plans in the labs, and those expected to implement them. This had the consequence that the plans kept being modified, and the benefits of concentrating on a few key issues were lost. Whatever the reasons, Tanzania needs to learn the lessons from what happened.
Last but not least, I think the time has come when we should all be careful how we advocate the “standard model” for countries like Tanzania. PFI (the Private Finance Initiative) is now thoroughly discredited in the UK, where it started, and from where it was promoted and exported to other countries. It led to many overpriced contracts. It trapped clients into very long-term links with contractors which were often dysfunctional and inflexible. The contractors themselves, such as Amey in the UK, are rushing to get out of PFI contracts before they have to meet very high costs towards the ends of their lives, or not meeting their obligations and having to cope with the resulting lack of trust and legal claims. It is very clear that contracting out can fail badly, sometimes if the client does not have the expertise to supervise the contract properly, or if the contractor is so determined to make money that costs are cut and quality is not maintained. More and more contracts are being brought back in-house (in the UK).

Advisors and academics should not advocate failing models to African countries, or at least not without very strong qualifications and warnings.

Sylvia Tamale on Feminist Pan-Africanism-25/09/2019

What is so Authentically African about Kitenge?

$
0
0
What is so Authentically African about Kitenge?


For both Africans and Africanists, African prints (from here on kitenge) tend to be a sentimental topic because of the symbolic value we attach to it. Very few studies on kitenge I have seen do go to the roots of historical development of the textiles industry and trade in Africa. It is in this context you find such an article - Can a Chinese import ever be authentically African? by April Zhu -  written with so much passion and a bit of romanticism without formulating the questions we should be asking about kitenge.

First, the lament of why the kitenge, our (supposed) cultural symbol and object is not produced in our respective countries (we don't usually go beyond the territory to say produced in Africa). This question other than awakening curiosity should not be a path to follow. This is for a simple fact that global circulation of capital and goods has been like that, especially after the rise of modern (overseas) empires. If we feel the urge to explain why we consume what we do not produce, then we may as well have to ask ourselves what do we produce and who consumes it, instead. We produce coffee, cotton, tea and many other raw materials. Do we therefore attach the same sentiments to our analysis of the raw materials we produce? Do you think somewhere in Belgium or Switzerland there is someone despairing about the chocolates they are famed for?

This question is also problematic because, first, it makes kitenge seem like a very important cultural symbol. What does it matter if I wear kitenge everyday and I am 31 years old, unmarried? Does kitenge come anywhere close to other symbols of accomplishment and success as cars, higher degrees and prestigious jobs? Fanon put this question to rest many years ago when he observed that those who hold onto cultural symbols seek to self-rehabilitate than to understand the cultural dynamics unfolding rights before them.

Second, concerning the historicity of kitenge, it still baffles me when I hear the cry about to whom it belongs without giving enough weight to the colonial and now neoliberal side of the story. It is not enough to say it comes from China; it could come from South Africa if the capitalists there are assured of their surplus. The colonial history of textile was of violence, especially in India, the biggest textiles producers at the time. In West Africa the scramble included competing and securing posts for supply of textiles in the 'hinterland'. I don't know who started that Holland and now China story because, by the time the Portuguese arrived in East Africa, there were trade routes all the way to Zimbabwe supplying textiles from India. Our postcolonial states only ventured into kitenge production because of the potentials for markets than it’s cultural value. (I can't speak for other countries but I know this about Tanzania). In short, we can worry about the cultural value but, historically, capital follows surplus.

Third, when we focus on the value kitenge has in our culture, we forget the other side of the story: production. What do we know about the industries that produce kitenge? If kitenge is so important in our sense of being as a people (of a society, nation or continent), should we not worry about the society whose poverty subjects them to unhealthy working conditions somewhere in Asia? It is probably produced in similar conditions as any other textiles. We should then extend our distress to our curtains, bedsheets and undergarments.

So, if we must ask why our kitenge is not produced locally, we ought to be able to juxtapose its social value with the history of imperialism and capitalism.

Coulson: On Synthesis of Institutional Diagnostic

$
0
0
This is Part 8 of a series of commentaries on Udadisi Blog entitled Tanzania Institutional Diagnostic: A Response and Comments By Andrew Coulson


Chapter 8. An Institutional Diagnostic of Tanzania: Synthesis


P.2 [of François Bourguignon and Samuel Wangwe’s Synthesis ] returns to “the uncertainty about what is and what could be the growth engine of Tanzania”. In the last 10 years, my observation is that gold, tourism, and mobile phones and their associated technologies, such as M-Pesa, have been growth engines. Along with the five large gold mines, a huge artisanal mining sector developed, employing a million people, almost all in an area that otherwise would have been depressed because of the failure of the cotton sector. The extreme price fluctuations in the price of gold are well known, but if the international economic system faces another crisis, as is likely, the value of gold will rise – so perhaps it is not a bad sector to be in (though more attention should be given to environmental consequences and health risks).
The growth in tourism benefitted otherwise challenged areas – areas accessed from Arusha and Zanzibar. It was assisted by political uncertainty in Kenya and the wars on its Northern border, and the opening up of opportunities for Tanzania to develop relationships with South Africa. Tourism is dependent on long-haul flights, but if the country remains stable it should continue to be dynamic.
The growth of mobile phone coverage and innovative uses has made Tanzania and Kenya world leaders in some aspects. There is no obvious reason why it should not continue. In addition, large areas of Southern and Western Tanzania experienced a green revolution with an unprecedented expansion of hybrid maize, cashewnuts, potatoes and flue-cured tobacco. Transport also expanded, especially local transport by daladalas (small buses) and motor cycles (in every village and along major roads). 
The big question is whether the country should have an industrial strategy which goes beyond creation of basic infrastructure, or whether it just leaves this to market forces. Justin Lin argues for a version of the Korean (or Ethiopian) strategy, finding tradeable products where the costs of production are a little below that of the main existing producers, and investing in those areas to supply world markets (with domestic markets only supplied incidentally – i.e. not the present strategy which is basically the colonial strategy of import substitution plus processing of agricultural or other products to increase the value added before export).
Murufuki et al.’s book point out that the governments in the Asian tigers played a key role in creating strategies and ensuring they were implemented. Tanzania briefly tried to emulate Malaysia, with Big Results Now (BRN), but Vietnam, with its period of socialist industrialisation is a better model. So far, I have seen little recognition that Tanzania can be competitive in some world markets (and has to be so if these are to be part of its growth engine) and has the single-minded determination to achieve that shown by the Asian tigers. Mufuruki understands this, which is why his book so interesting.

The well-written section on corruption reinforces points made in Chapter 1 and elsewhere.
The point on p.6 about the need for much stronger regulatory bodies is very correct. But to work they need a functioning legal system, and skilled and experienced staff who can collect evidence and present it in court successfully when faced with extremely hostile and highly-paid barristers. It also requires a willingness to face local vested interests i.e. those who have no wish to be regulated. The failure of the attempts to maintain cotton production in the Lake areas by introducing contract farming is a good case in point: the efforts of the regulator (the Cotton Board) were sabotaged by small private ginners who were prepared to buy and sell low quality adulterated cotton.
Chambi Chachage’s thesis has much to say on the slow emergence of an African business class, and, overall, its preference for making money from trade or the media to traditional manufacturing.
The points about centralisation bias and the distrust of market mechanisms and the private sector are extremely well taken. There needs to be a willingness to let go, to trust other people provided institutional systems are in place that will deal with irregularities or crimes when these are identified. The private sector itself will have to take more centre stage than it has been allowed to, at any time in Tanganyika or Tanzania’s history. That is why Mufuruki’s and Chambi’s works are so significant.

How good is the Barrick deal with Tanzania?

$
0
0
How good is the deal between Barrick and the Government of Tanzania?


Dastan Kweka

The Government of Tanzania and the mining giant – Barrick Gold Corporation – have finally entered into an agreement that, if implemented fully and smoothly, will settle more than two years of a bitter confrontation between Barrick’s subsidiary – Acacia Mining PLC, and the eastern African nation. In Mid July, Acacia disclosed a draft agreement containing the proposed terms of its acquisition by Barrick, and thus sent a signal that a breakthrough had been achieved, after nearly a year of disagreement, and resistance.
The “recommended final offer” that was disclosed in July provided for the terms of acquisition of Acacia`s shares – about 36% - that weren`t already owned by the parent company, as a mechanism for buying the subsidiary out of Tanzania, and thus ending a protracted business stalemate that the subsidiary had grappled with since, at least, early 2017. Now that the agreement between Barrick and the Government of Tanzania has become effective, stakeholders can take time to reflect on the lessons that the country might draw from a heroic attempt to capture a fair share of benefits from its growing extractive sector.
The “recommended final offer” that was released to shareholders by Acacia, for information and consultation purposes, included an overview of the framework of Barrick`s agreement with the government of Tanzania. The content of the framework (though the final version may have changed slightly) can be seen as symbolizing the extent to which the Government of Tanzania, through its mysterious negotiation team (GNT), was able (or unable) to make, and defend its case. This article draws, in part, from that content, and other associated developments. Before examining the terms of the framework agreement, and the lessons that the entire confrontation can offer, let me highlight, albeit in passing, a background to the rift between Acacia Mining PLC, and the Government of Tanzania.
Overview of the GoT – Acacia rift
Conflict between Acacia and the Government of Tanzania (GoT) worsened in early 2017 when public authorities, acting on orders from the state house, barred the company from exporting a consignment of about 277 gold/copper concentrates containers. This decision was followed by formation of two Presidential committees – the first (also known as Prof. Mruma committee), was announced in March, 2017, and tasked with investigating the type and quantity of the minerals in the containers, while the second (Prof. Osoro committee), which was established in the following month, was given a quite broad mandate. It looked into the legality of the entire gold/copper concentrates export arrangement between the government and Acacia, and sought to determine if the government was receiving its fair share of revenues. This task included reviewing the respective contracts and advising the government on necessary improvements. The committee was also required to determine the number of mineral sand containers that had been exported between 1998 and 2017, provide an estimate of revenues that the government was entitled to obtain, and compare that with what was actually received. The difference would, eventually, constitute a huge debt that Acacia would be asked to settle.
The findings of both investigations are (now) well known. The first committee, which also investigated the conduct of the Tanzania Mineral Audit Agency (TMAA), a public entity that was responsible for inspecting and certifying mineral sand consignments for export, claimed that there was a high quantity of gold, and other valuable minerals – copper, silver, iron, and sulphur – than initially declared by Acacia, and that the government of Tanzania was losing billions of money in revenues. As if that was not enough, the committee added that, the value of iron, sulphur and “strategic minerals” was never considered in royalty calculations. TMAA was seen as incompetent or complicit (or both) – its fate was sealed. As expected, Acacia disputed the findings, citing “more than 20 years of data available” to them, and called for an “independent review of the content of the concentrates.”
The second committee argued, in its findings, that Acacia had neither been registered in Tanzania nor obtained a certificate of compliance from local authorities, as required by the law, and while the company claimed to own three subsidiaries in the country, no documents proving ownership or interest in any of them had been submitted to authorities. As such, the company had not qualified to receive a mining license and could not (legally) engage in mineral business in the country. Government of Tanzania would, subsequently, stick to this finding in refusing to engage Acacia, and instead, preferred to negotiate with its parent company – Barrick Gold Corporation. Apart from the registration status of the company, the second committee accused Acacia of under-declaring revenues, and thus denying the country huge sums of resources. The company, in its defiant response, disputed these findings too, citing its supposedly huge archive of data which, allegedly, showed a different revenue trend. It is this disagreement between Acacia and the GoT that makes the terms of the framework agreement between Barrick and GoT interesting, and worthy of analysis.
A humiliating defeat?
The “draft” agreement between the GoT and Barrick that was released in July, and became operational in September, included a caveat that there were several “substantive” issues that had not been settled, and that the final deal would, possibly, be significantly different. Although the final agreement is not public, it is logical to assume that any subsequent adjustments did not radically alter the key foundations of the deal (the agreement became effective two months after it was disclosed – an indication that it’s foundations remained intact). As such, it is safe to use the public version of the framework agreement for analysis purposes.

An examination of the framework agreement reveals that the government of Tanzania agreed to a, surprisingly, quite far-reaching agreement – “a comprehensive settlement of all disputes between the GoT and the Acacia Group” – whose effect will be to “release and forever discharge one another (and their respective related persons) from all and any Claims that they have ever had, now have or hereafter can, shall or may have against one another or their related persons …” (see page 72). In other words, Barrick negotiated so hard to ensure it did not inherit a single dispute or liability from Acacia. With this clause, years of public complaints about human rights abuse, unfair compensation cases and concerns over environmental pollution that had been raised against Acacia were extinguished – just like that!
The framework agreement also indicates that the government was unable to prove or sufficiently defend any of its substantive accusations against Acacia. For instance, one of the key assumptions under the “settlement terms” of the deal reads, “neither party admits any liability or wrongdoing whatsoever.” (see page 73). This points to a mutual compromise that was, most likely, induced by a serious deadlock in negotiation, and reaffirms doubts about the credibility of the evidence gathered by the two (Mruma & Osorro) Presidential committees. Also, the assumption gives a clue as to why a $190 billion tax bill imposed on Acacia was later reduced to a mere “aggregate sum” of $300 million, to be paid in six installments, “in consideration for the full, final and complete settlement of the disputes and liability to taxation…” Below is a summary of other key provisions from the agreement;
A key setback regarding the “50/50” split is its broad definition as indicated in the table. Such a broad definition contradicts what Prof. Kabudi communicated (watch from 0.55) to the nation in October 2017 when he sought to clarify what seemed to be the agreement at the time. He stated that the 50/50 split would come from profit minerals (after companies had paid all statutory taxes i.e. royalties, corporate income tax etc). In the end, Kabudi accepted a formula he had initially rejected.
The following are few observations from my analysis of the agreement;

- It seems that the spirit of the agreement, from the government`s point of view, was to draw a line under all that had happened (possibly after a deadlock in negotiation). Expelling Acacia was a key step in initiating a “new” (though rough) start. This has been the only clear victory to date.

Notably, confrontation with Acacia raised the profile of the country as a risky place to invest in, and it may take a while before we realize the full scale of the consequences arising from negative coverage that took place across the world.

- A deadlock in negotiation must have emanated from a disagreement over data on mineral composition as well as production trends (and subsequent difference of opinion on tax implications). Acacia had questioned the findings of the first committee, as soon as they were released, and there is no indication that the company changed its position. Surprisingly, some “former” TMAA officers were aware that the findings of the first committee, especially on mineral composition, were highly questionable, but nobody was willing to listen to them (they were suspects, after all). I still think that the decision to disband TMAA, and not use its officials in pursuing the case was wrong. TMAA had built its capacity over the years, through “learning by doing” and should have been reformed, not disbanded.

- It is clear from the agreement that Barrick representatives (most likely acting on instructions from Acacia) sought to clear the names, and secure the release of (Acacia`s) former employees as well as associates that got into trouble following a deterioration of the business relationship (see page 72). Beneficiaries will most likely include Deo Mwanyika, and Asa Mwaipopo– both of whom are languishing in jail. But will they be required to plead guilty in return for amnesty, as has been the case with those accused of economic crimes? This will be the first, significant test to the agreement.

It is important to note that the agreement is (though rightly) silent about how the government will treat its own citizens that were caught in the net, either for being considered complicit or incompetent (or both). Former employees of the Tanzania Mineral Audit Agency (TMAA), some zonal mining officers, and others, that were roughed up, and/or detained, deserve restitution. It`s hard to see how a case against any of them will stand, in light of the huge concession that the government made in its negotiation with Barrick.
So how bad is the deal?
Analysis by Haki Rasilimali, a network of CSOs working on natural resource governance concluded that the agreement was “a bad deal that will leave Tanzania worse off than before.” ACT Wazalendo, a vibrant opposition party has also questioned the content of the agreement, as well as the manner in which it was reached i.e.; parliament was left in the dark, even though it was central in passing tougher legislations in 2017.

Both analyses combined a reflection on what the government promised but failed to achieve, possibly for feasibility reasons i.e. $300 million upfront payment, construction of smelter (cf. news about Tanzania awarding licenses for the construction of a mineral smelter and two gold refineries to Chinese firms), permanent ban on export of concentrates, as well as allowing International arbitration (contrary to a law passed in 2017), with “genuine” concessions such as waiver of obligation to float shares in DSE (though the feasibility of this could also be questioned on the basis of weak local purchasing power). This combination means that the analyses failed to discount what was not feasible, and achievable (and which ends up skewing their conclusions). Most importantly, the analyses do not acknowledge the limitations arising from the apparent government failure to prove its case.
To undertake a reasonably balanced analysis, one has to separate what was considered desirable but possibly not feasible, from “genuine” concessions. Below is an attempt to do so;
A close examination of the agreement between Barrick Gold Corp and GoT points to a possibility that the deal might be fairly good, in light of the indication that the government failed, though heroically, in proving it’s case i.e. that it was being short-changed. To be able to say, with certainty, whether this was a bad deal or not, one will have to model the results, or wait for clues in EITI reports. For now, the jury is (still) out!
Viewing all 468 articles
Browse latest View live